The Cost of Household Services, Alberta, 2018: A Survey

by Christopher J. Bruce and Jody Prevost

The cost of hiring individuals to perform household services such as housecleaning, snow removal, and handyman repairs can amount to a significant percentage of the damages in a personal injury or fatal accident claim. Yet, despite the importance of these costs, reliable estimates of the components of a household services claim are very difficult to obtain. In order to assist the court in this respect, Economica has conducted a number of surveys of household services costs since 1997.

In those surveys, for example, we found that the average hourly cost of housecleaners in Calgary rose from approximately $13.50 in 1997, to $30.00 in 2014; and for handymen the rates rose from $24.00 in 1997 to $35.00 in 2014.

As four years have passed since our last survey, and as our experience suggests that rates tend to increase appreciably over time, we undertook a new survey of providers in 2018. In each case, we conducted exhaustive searches of relevant quotes using Kijiji and Google (the two most common sources of advertisements). This article summarises our findings.

Housecleaning

Using the internet, we identified sixteen professional agencies (for example, Mango Maids) in Calgary and fourteen in Edmonton that provide house cleaning; and we identified six ads from individuals (on Kijiji) in Calgary and seven in Edmonton.

In Calgary, the average rate among professional agencies was $41.38 per hour, with a range from $25.00 to $56.80. The comparable average for Edmonton was $39.28, ranging from $25.00 to $65.66. Among those individuals who advertised on sites such as Kijiji, the average hourly rate in Calgary was $26.67 and in Edmonton was $30.57.

In the smaller cities, most of our data came from Kijiji. In those cities, the average hourly rates (with numbers of ads in brackets) were: Lethbridge (6), $29.16; Red Deer (7), $29.71; Medicine Hat (5), $29.00; and Grande Prairie (7), $29.30.

We conclude that rates for individual suppliers average approximately $29.00 per hour across all Alberta cities; and that comparable rates for professional agencies average approximately $40.00 per hour (where such services are available).

These data raise two important question: first, if individuals listed on Kijiji charge approximately $29 per hour, why do consumers hire professional agencies at $11 per hour more than that? Second, why do the rates for individual suppliers exceed the hourly wages paid to individuals who work for professional agencies?

Professional agencies versus individuals

We suspect that the answer to the first of these questions derives from three factors.

First, agencies may be able to offer a higher quality of service than can private individuals. For example, they might provide training to their employees, use screening interviews to select the most skilled workers, or offer to replace workers who proved to be unacceptable to the client.

Second, it is possible that agencies might be able to complete their tasks more quickly than would private contractors, thereby lowering the effective hourly rate of the former.

Finally, commercial firms may be better able than individual cleaners to develop reputations for reliable service. If a cleaner is sick or otherwise unable to work, a firm can often replace that individual with another employee; whereas if self-employed individuals are unable to meet their commitments, their jobs go undone. Customers may be willing to pay a premium for the more reliable service.

Regardless of the answer to this question, however, the fact is that it would be very difficult to hire a reliable housecleaner in Calgary or Edmonton for less than $30 per hour – and that cost would rise to more than $40 per hour if the client wished to hire a bonded cleaning service.

Self-employed suppliers versus employees

A second puzzle raised by our findings is that, according to the Alberta Wage and Salary Survey, “light duty cleaners” earned an average of $16.08 per hour in 2017, with a range of $12.75—$20.13, more than $10.00 per hour less than the rates charged by individuals advertising on Kijiji. What is the source of this differential? One possibility is that the individuals identified by the Survey are working as employees for large cleaning companies and, therefore, have security of employment; whereas those advertising on Kijiji are self-employed, with the attendant uncertainties and with the requirement, in many cases, that they provide their own cleaning supplies. Another possibility is that it is the more productive, reliable individuals who choose self-employment. Regardless of the answer, our evidence suggests that individual plaintiffs will not be able to hire housecleaners at the wage found in the Alberta Wage and Salary Survey. It is the rates found on Kijiji and on the websites of professional agencies that best reflect the cost of hiring a housecleaner for an hour.

A caveat

It should be noted, however, that even if it costs, say, $30 to hire a housecleaner for one hour, it does not follow that it will cost $30 to replace one hour of a plaintiff’s time. The reason for this is that professional cleaners may be able to complete more work in an hour than could non-professionals (i.e. than plaintiffs). The best information we have available, for example, suggests that this differential is approximately 25 percent; that is, to replace one of the plaintiff’s hours will require only 0.75 hours of a professional’s time. In this case, the cost of replacing an hour will be $22.50 (= 0.75 x $30). [Note: this argument with respect to the greater efficiency of professional providers applies to all of the other services identified in this report, except child care.]

Handyman

With respect to handyman services, we obtained quotes from Yelp, Google and Kijiji. In each case, we requested a quote to “replace several fence boards, clean and repair the gutters, and paint the step rails and trim.”

In Calgary, where we received responses from four individuals and five professional companies, the average hourly rate was $45.28. Three companies had minimum charges of two hours.

In Edmonton, where we received responses from six professional companies and four individuals, the average hourly rate was $47.50. Only two companies specified a minimum number of hours billed.

In both cities, the preponderance of quotes fell between $40.00 and $50.00.

 Lawn care and snow removal

Lawn care

In our search for lawn care rates in Calgary and Edmonton we asked for quotes for a 2400 square foot lot with an 1800 square foot house, front and back. Of sixteen lawn care companies surveyed in Calgary, fifteen ads were from professional companies and one from an individual. In Edmonton, of fourteen lawn care companies surveyed, eleven were from professional services and three from individuals.

In Calgary the average cost was $36.73 per visit for lawn care and $200 per month for lawn cutting. In Edmonton these rates were $46.63 and $157.80, respectively.

Snow removal

With respect to snow removal, we surveyed businesses in Calgary and Edmonton for quotes to remove snow from a home with a two-car driveway, stairs, entry, and city sidewalk.

Twelve companies in Calgary responded, with an average per visit rate of $36.33 and a monthly “unlimited” rate of $176.05. In Edmonton, eleven companies responded, with an average per visit rate of $41.14 and a monthly “on demand program” of $182.05.

Child care

We identified six methods of providing (commercial) child care: day care, day home, live-in nanny, live-out nanny, before- and after-school care, and (hourly) babysitting. We obtained all of our information from Google and kijiji.

Day homes

We identified six day homes in Calgary and nine in Edmonton. In Calgary, the rates averaged $57.50 per day, or $845 per month; whereas the comparable rates in Edmonton were $45 per day, or $759 per month.

Day care

Our findings with respect to the monthly cost of day care are reported in Table 1. There, we provide rates by four age groups: infants (0 to 18 months), pre-toddlers (18-24 months), toddlers (24-36 months) and pre-school (four and five years).

Before- and after-school care

The average monthly rate for before- and after-school care, for children in grades one to six, was found to be $532 per month in Calgary (nine agencies) and $603 in Edmonton (six agencies).

Nannies

The average monthly rate for the three live-in nannies we identified in Calgary was $2,466, and for three live-out nannies it was $3,200. We also obtained hourly rates, averaging $17.50 (approximately $3,500 per month) for fifteen live-out nannies in Calgary.

In Edmonton, the monthly rate for the six live-in nannies we identified was $2,300; and for the five live-out nannies in our survey it was $2,600. We were also able to obtain hourly wages for fifteen live-in and fifteen live-out nannies in Edmonton. The average rates for those samples were $16.00 and $16.47, respectively (approximately $3,200 and $3,300 per month, respectively).

Babysitting

In each of Calgary and Edmonton, we obtained twenty quotes for babysitting services. In each city, eleven of the quotes came from Kijiji and nine came from a website called nannyservices.ca. The average hourly quote from Kijiji was $14.55 in Calgary and $13.23 in Edmonton. The average quote from nannyservices was $15.77 in Calgary and $16.33 in Edmonton. In both cities and for both sources, the most common rate was $15 per hour. (The slightly higher rate from nannyservices appears to have arisen because many of the individuals advertising on that site offered ancillary services such as dog walking and light housekeeping.)

 Home care and meal preparation

Generalized home care services range in price by the level of assistance required. We obtained information from five professional agencies in Calgary and Edmonton – Home Care Assistance Calgary, Miraculum Home Care, Wild Rose Caregivers, Classic Life Care, and Paramed Home Health – concerning the costs of caring for “a relative that had been injured in an accident and was recuperating at home”.

Home Care Assistance Calgary provided quotes for both daily and monthly care for: meal preparation, light housekeeping, grocery shopping, grooming and dressing, bathing assistance and in some cases medical assistance. Their rates were $128 per day for part-time care and $256 per day for full-time care. Weekly rates varied from $384 to $1,792; and monthly rates from $1,164 to $7,765, depending on the number of hours required.

We found that hourly rates for the five agencies varied according to the qualifications of the workers who were required. Health care aides cost from $27 to $32 per hour; licensed practical nurses approximately $37 per hour; and registered nurses approximately $60 per hour.

We also obtained rates from individuals advertising on the website nannyservices.ca. Searching under companion and health care aide, we found that health care aides and personal service workers charge an average hourly rate of $21 in Calgary and $18 in Edmonton. In both cities, full time services cost $2,800 per month.

Summary

In this article, we have reported the results of a survey of household services providers in Alberta. Two outcomes are very clear. First, it is inappropriate to use a single, hourly rate to evaluate all such services. Whereas child care services cost less than $10 per hour, ($45 to $57 per day), housecleaning services cost almost $30 per hour, and lawn care and snow removal cost over $35 per visit.

Second, the convention of using $12 to $16 per hour for household services is unsupportable. With the exception of child care, all of the services that were identified in our survey cost significantly more than that, even after allowing for the greater efficiency of professionals.

Our findings also strongly support the view that hourly rates for housekeeping services should not be obtained by simply averaging the figures that have been adopted in previous cases. We are pleased to note that Madame Justice D. C. Read agreed with our conclusion on the latter point in her decision in Palmquist v. Ziegler, 2010 ABQB 337, at para [271] (emphasis added):

By using an average of numbers accepted in other cases in order to establish a number used to make an assumption in this case, all of the possible errors, either of the trial judge or of the economists who gave evidence in those cases, are incorporated into the number to be used in this case. Courts rely upon economists to determine what assumptions are reasonable to make and their decisions are only as reasonable as are the assumptions used. I have no means of evaluating the expert evidence that was before those other courts to determine whether or not I accept the assumptions made. It is circular to accept that an average of numbers accepted by another courts has any validity in respect to the issue of what economic assumptions are reasonable for me to make in this case.

Proposal

Statistics Canada provides data concerning the amounts of time spent on six types of “household work and related activities.” These are: cooking/washing up, house cleaning and laundry, maintenance and repair, other household work, shopping for goods and services, and primary child care. For the purposes of calculating the costs of household services, in our reports we will combine “cooking/washing up” with “shopping” and evaluate that category at the approximate average rate for home care and meal preparation, $32.00 per hour (up from $25.00 per hour in our 2014 survey).

We will combine “maintenance and repair” with “other household work” (a large portion of which consists of “gardening and ground work”) and evaluate the resulting services at the landscaping, snow removal, and handyman services rate of approximately $38.00 per hour (up from $35.00 in 2010).

We will evaluate “house cleaning and laundry” at the rate for housecleaning services. For the purposes of our reports, we propose to use the conservative rate of $29.00 per hour in all regions of Alberta (down from $30 per hour in Calgary and Edmonton in 2014, but up from $25.00 per hour elsewhere).

For each of the preceding services, however, we will assume that professionals will be 25 percent more efficient than the plaintiff would have been. Hence, our assumption is that the cost of those services is 25 percent less than the rate that has been quoted per hour.

We will assume that it in Calgary it costs $1,200 per month to care for each infant (the approximate mid-point of day care and home care costs), or $900 in Edmonton; $1,000 to care for each toddler/pre-school child in Calgary, ($800 in Edmonton); and $525 per month to provide before- and after-school care for each school-aged child in Calgary ($600 in Edmonton).

Finally, for the purposes of quantifying child care costs on an hourly basis, we propose to employ $15.00 per hour, (the most common rate quoted for babysitting in Calgary and Edmonton).

leaf

Christopher Bruce is the President of Economica; he has a PhD in economics from  the University of Cambridge

Jody Prevost is the administrative assistant at Economica

 

The Cost of Household Services, Alberta 2014: A Survey

by Christopher J. Bruce and Russette S. Pack

The cost of hiring individuals to perform household services such as housecleaning, snow removal, and handyman repairs can amount to a significant percentage of the damages in a personal injury or fatal accident claim. Yet, despite the importance of these costs, reliable estimates of the components of a household services claim are very difficult to obtain. In order to assist the court in this respect, Economica has conducted a number of surveys of household services costs since 1997.

In those surveys, for example, we found that the hourly cost of housecleaners in Edmonton and Calgary rose from approximately $13.50 in 1997, to $25.00 in 2006, and to $30.00 in 2010; and for handymen the rates rose from $24.00 in 1997 to $32.00 in 2006, and then fell to $30.00 in 2010.

As four years have passed since our last survey, and as our experience suggests that rates tend to increase appreciably over time, we have undertaken a survey of providers for 2014. This article summarises our main findings.

I. Housecleaning

Using the internet, we identified five professional agencies (for example, The Clean Team) in Calgary and four in Edmonton that provide house cleaning; and we identified fourteen ads from individuals (usually on Kijiji) in Calgary and seventeen in Edmonton.

In Calgary, the average rate among professional agencies was $34.40 per hour, with a range from $25.00 to $45.00.

The comparable average for Edmonton was $47.75, with a range from $34.00 to $57.00. Among those individuals who advertised on websites such as Kijiji, the average hourly rate in Calgary was $23.85 and in Edmonton was $24.32, (with almost half of the rates at exactly $25.00).

In the smaller cities, almost all of our data came from Kijiji ads. In those cities, the average hourly rates (with numbers of ads in brackets) were: Lethbridge (6), $24.16; Red Deer (7), $22.14; Medicine Hat (5), $24.50; and Grande Prairie (7), $25.00.

II. Handyman (maintenance) services

We obtained the names of handyman services in Calgary and Edmonton primarily from Kijiji. In each case, we attempted to obtain quotes to: “replace several fence boards, clean and repair the gutters, and paint the step rails and trim.” If those rates were not available in the ads, we phoned to obtain them.

The average hourly rate among nine services in Calgary was $31.77; whereas the average in Edmonton, among eight services, was $26.06. In both cities, more than half of the responses fell between $20.00 and $30.00, with the difference in the cities’ averages resulting primarily because a larger number of individuals quoted more than $30.00 per hour in Calgary (four out of nine) than in Edmonton (one out of eight).

III. Lawn care and snow removal

Again, lawn care and snow removal firms were identified from Kijiji ads in Calgary and Edmonton. With respect to lawn care, we asked for a quote on a suburban city lot (4,200 square-foot lot with an 1,800 square-foot, two-story home) with lawn in front and back.

With respect to snow removal, we obtained quotes for a house with a two car driveway, stairs, entry, and a city sidewalk. In all cases, firms quoted either per attendance at the home or per month (i.e. not per hour).

The fifteen lawn care firms in Calgary charged an average of $37.80 per attendance (with seven between $35 and $40) and the ten firms in Edmonton averaged $34.25 (with six at $30).

With respect to snow removal, the six Calgary firms that charged per visit averaged $38.75, whereas the eight that charged a flat rate per month averaged $160.00.

In Edmonton, we identified five firms, all of which charged a flat monthly rate, averaging $142 per month.

IV. Childcare

We identified five methods of providing (commercial) child care: day care, day home, live-in nanny, live-out nanny, and before- and after-school care. We obtained all of our information from various internet sites.

The numbers of day cares and day homes that were contacted in Calgary and Edmonton, and their average monthly fees, are reported in Table 1.

There it is seen that day homes charge approximately $700 to $800 per month for all ages of children; and that day cares charge approximately $1,200 to $1,300 per month for infants and from $900 to $1,200 for other age groups.

The average monthly rate for the twelve live-in nannies we identified in Calgary was $2,300; and for thirteen live-out nannies (also in Calgary) it was $2,518. (These individuals reported hourly rates of $13.08 and $16.55, respectively.) In Edmonton, many nannies only reported hourly rates. Assuming that those rates applied to forty-four hour weeks, the twelve live-in nannies charged an average of $2,053 per month ($11.66 per hour) and the eleven live-out nannies charged $2,464 ($14.00 per hour).

The average monthly rate for before- and after-school care was found to be $430 in Calgary (nine agencies) and $480 in Edmonton (YMCA).

V. Homecare and meal preparation

We were able to identify four agencies in Calgary that provide generalized home care services, such as meal preparation, light housekeeping, grocery and clothes shopping, grooming and dressing, bed-making, and bathing. In each case, we sought a quote for “a relative that had been injured in an accident and was recuperating at home.” The average hourly rate among these agencies was $21.50. In Edmonton, we found four individuals who charged an average of $19.50 per hour.

In addition, CBI Health quoted $29.00 per hour for assisting a relative “who had been injured in an accident and was recuperating at home;” and Alberta Health Service (AHS) indicated that they would provide: in home meal preparation for $25.00-$30.00 per hour; personal care (including bathing and dressing) for $23.00-$30.00 per hour; and twenty-four hour live-in care for $23.00-$27.00 per hour. (Skilled nursing would cost $38.00-$75.00 per hour from AHS).

VI. Hourly rate proposal

Statistics Canada provides data concerning the amounts of time spent on six types of “household work and related activities.” These are: cooking/washing up, house cleaning and laundry, maintenance and repair, other household work, shopping for goods and services, and primary child care.

For the purposes of calculating the costs of household services, in our reports we will combine “cooking/washing up” with “shopping” and evaluate that category at the approximate average rate for home care and meal preparation, $25.00 per hour (up from $20.00 per hour in our 2005 survey, but the same as the rate we obtained from our 2010 survey).

We will combine “maintenance and repair” with “other household work” (a large portion of which consists of “gardening and ground work”) and evaluate the resulting services at the landscaping, snow removal, and handyman services rate of approximately $35.00 per hour (up from $30.00 in 2010).

We will evaluate “house cleaning and laundry” at the rate for housecleaning services. For the purposes of our reports, we propose to use the conservative rate of $30.00 per hour in Calgary and Edmonton, and $25.00 per hour elsewhere (compared to $30.00 and $20.00, respectively, in 2010).

For each of the preceding services, however, we will assume that professionals will be 25 percent more efficient than the plaintiff would have been. Hence, our assumption is that the cost of those services is 25 percent less than the rate that has been quoted per hour.

Finally, we will assume that it costs $1,000 per month to care for each baby (the approximate mid-point of day care and home care costs), $900 to care for each toddler/pre-school child, and $450 per month to provide before- and after-school care for each school-aged child (up from $850, $800, and $400, respectively, in 2010).

For the purposes of quantifying child care costs on an hourly basis, we propose to employ $10.00 per hour.

VII. Discussion

The data discussed in this article raise an important question: if individuals listed on Kijiji charge approximately $25 per hour, why do consumers hire professional agencies at $10 to $15 per hour more than that? We suspect that the answer to this question derives from three factors.

First, agencies may be able to offer a higher quality of service than can private individuals. For example, they might provide training to their employees, use screening interviews to select the most skilled workers, or offer to replace workers who proved to be unacceptable to the client.

Second, it is possible that agencies might be able to complete their tasks more quickly than would private contractors, thereby lowering the effective hourly rate of the former.

Finally, commercial firms may be better able than individual cleaners to develop reputations for reliable service. If a cleaner is sick or otherwise unable to work, a firm can often replace that individual with another employee; whereas if self-employed individuals are unable to meet their commitments, their jobs go undone. Customers may be willing to pay a premium for the more reliable service.

Regardless of the answer to this question, however, the fact is that it would be very difficult to hire, say, a reliable housecleaner in Calgary or Edmonton for less than $25 per hour – and that cost would rise to more than $35 per hour if the client wished to hire a bonded cleaning service.

It should be noted, however, that even if it costs, say, $25 per hour to hire a housecleaner, it does not follow that it will cost $25 to replace one hour of a plaintiff’s time. The reason for this is that professional cleaners may be able to complete more work in an hour than could non-professionals. The best information we have available, for example, suggests that this differential is approximately 25 percent; that is, to replace one of the plaintiff’s hours will require only 0.75 hours of a professional’s time. In this case, the cost of replacing an hour will be $18.75 (= 0.75 × $25). [Note: this argument with respect to the greater efficiency of professional providers applies to all of the other services identified in this report, except child care.]

A further puzzle raised by our findings is that, according to the Alberta Wage and Salary Survey, “light duty cleaners” earned an average of $14.76 per hour in 2013, with a range of $13.76-$16.43, almost $10.00 per hour less than the rates charged by individuals advertising on Kijiji. What is the source of this differential?

One possibility is that the individuals identified by the Survey are working as employees for large cleaning companies and, therefore, have security of employment; whereas those advertising on Kijiji are self-employed, with the attendant uncertainties.

Another possibility is that it is the more productive, reliable individuals who choose self-employment.

Regardless of the answer, our evidence suggests that individual consumers will not be able to hire housecleaners at the wage found in the Alberta Wage and Salary Survey. It is the rates found on Kijiji and on the websites of professional agencies that best reflect the cost to a plaintiff of hiring a housecleaner for an hour.

VIII. Summary

In this article, we have reported the results of a survey of household services providers in Alberta. Two outcomes are very clear. First, it is inappropriate to use a single, hourly rate to evaluate all such services. Whereas child care services cost approximately $10.00-$15.00 per hour, housecleaning services cost more than $25 per hour, and lawn care and snow removal can cost over $35 per visit.

Second, the convention of using $12 to $16 per hour for household services is unsupportable. All of the services that were identified in our survey cost significantly more than that, even after allowing for the greater efficiency of professionals.

Our findings also suggest that it may be inappropriate to rely on the wage rates reported by the Alberta Wage and Salary Survey (or other sources of average wage rates) to estimate the costs of services such as housecleaning. Whereas the wages for that occupation average approximately $15 per hour, the individual housecleaners we identified through Kijiji charged more than $25.00 per hour on average; and housecleaning agencies charged $25.00-$50.00 per hour (more than twice the wage that Statistics Canada reports).

Finally, we are of the opinion that hourly rates for housekeeping services should not be obtained by averaging the figures that have been adopted in previous cases.

We are pleased to note that Madame Justice D. C. Read agreed with our conclusion on this point in her decision in Palmquist v. Ziegler, 2010 ABQB 337, at para [271] (emphasis added):

By using an average of numbers accepted in other cases in order to establish a number used to make an assumption in this case, all of the possible errors, either of the trial judge or of the economists who gave evidence in those cases, are incorporated into the number to be used in this case. Courts rely upon economists to determine what assumptions are reasonable to make and their decisions are only as reasonable as are the assumptions used. I have no means of evaluating the expert evidence that was before those other courts to determine whether or not I accept the assumptions made. It is circular to accept that an average of numbers accepted by another courts has any validity in respect to the issue of what economic assumptions are reasonable for me to make in this case.

To view our previous articles related to the costs of household services (or other articles of interest to personal injury law), please visit our website, www.economica.ca, or call our office at 403-297-0012.

leaf

Christopher Bruce is the President of Economica and a Professor of Economics at the University of Calgary. He is also the author of Assessment of Personal Injury Damages (Butterworths, 2004).

Russette Pack is Economica’s administrative assistant.

The Cost of Household Services, Alberta, 2010: A Survey

by Amelia Lamb and Christopher Bruce

In 2005, Economica conducted a survey of the cost of obtaining household services (see The Expert Witness, Vol. 11, No. 2, Summer 2006). At that time, we found that housecleaners in Calgary and Edmonton charged approximately $25.00 per hour; and that handymen charged approximately $33.00 per hour.

Since that time, we have estimated the current costs of household services by increasing the 2005 estimates by the intervening rate of inflation in Alberta. This implies, for example, that our estimate of the cost of housecleaners was approximately $27.50 per hour in 2010.

Increasingly, however, we have become aware that our estimates differ from the rates that prevail in Alberta, particularly in Calgary and Edmonton. The informal evidence available to us suggests, for example, that many housecleaners now charge more than $30 per hour.

For this reason, in late 2009 and early 2010 we conducted a new survey of household costs. In this survey, we obtained housecleaning, handyman, landscaping and snow removal, child care, and home care/meal preparation rates from a large sample of agencies and individuals in both Calgary and Edmonton, and housecleaning rates for smaller samples in Lethbridge, Grande Prairie, Red Deer, and Medicine Hat. We report the results of that survey in this article.

1. Housecleaning

Using the internet, we identified five professional agencies (for example, Molly Maid) in Calgary and four in Edmonton that provide house cleaning; and we identified nineteen Kijiji or Craigslist ads (usually from individuals) in Calgary and twenty-five in Edmonton. In each case, we attempted to obtain an hourly rate to clean a 1600 square foot, two story house, assuming there were no pets and that the cleaner would not be responsible for the basement.

In Calgary, the average rate among professional agencies was $36.63 per hour, with a range from $24.00 to $45.00. The comparable average for Edmonton was $34.50, with a range from $20.00 to $41.25. Among those who advertised on Kijiji or Craigslist, the average hourly rate was $23.76 in Calgary and $23.44 in Edmonton, (with over seventy percent of the rates falling between $20.00 and $25.00).

In the smaller cities, all of our data came from Kijiji or Craigslist ads. In those cities, the average hourly rates (with numbers of ads in brackets) were: Lethbridge (16), $20.81; Red Deer (7), $20.00; Medicine Hat (4), $23.75; and Grande Prairie (7), $18.71.

An important question is raised by the deviation between the rates charged by professional services and those by individuals: if individuals charge, say, $20 to $25 per hour, and agencies charge $30 to $40 per hour, why do clients hire the professional firms?

We suspect that the answer to this question derives from three factors: First, agencies may be able to offer a higher quality of service than can private individuals. For example, they might provide training to their employees, use screening interviews to select the most skilled workers, or offer to replace workers who proved to be unacceptable to the client.

Second, it is possible that agencies might be able to complete their tasks more quickly than will private contractors, thereby lowering the effective hourly rate of the former.

Finally, commercial firms may be better able than individual cleaners to develop reputations for reliable service. If a cleaner is sick or otherwise unable to work, a firm can often replace that individual with another employee; whereas if self-employed individuals are unable to meet their commitments, their jobs go undone. Customers may be willing to pay a premium for the more reliable service.

Regardless of the answer to this question, however, the fact is that it would be very difficult to hire a reliable housecleaner in Calgary or Edmonton for less than $20 per hour – and that cost would rise to more than $30 per hour if the client wished to hire a bonded cleaning service.

2. Handyman

We obtained the names of handyman services in Calgary and Edmonton from Kijiji and Craigslist. In each case, we attempted to obtain quotes to: “replace several fence boards, clean and repair the gutters, and paint the step rails and trim.” If those rates were not available in the ads, we phoned to obtain them. The average hourly rate among twenty-six services in Calgary was $24.88; whereas the average in Edmonton, among twenty-one services, was $29.24. In both cities, approximately half of the responses fell between $20.00 and $30.00, with the difference in the cities’ averages resulting primarily because a larger number of individuals quoted less than $20.00 per hour in Calgary (nine out of twenty-six) than in Edmonton (two out of twenty-one).

3. Lawn care and snow removal

Again, lawn care and snow removal firms were identified from Kijiji and Craigslist ads in Calgary and Edmonton. With respect to lawn care, we asked for a quote on a suburban city lot (4200 sq ft lot with an 1800 sq ft two story home) with lawn in front and back. With respect to snow removal, we obtained quotes for a house with a two car driveway, stairs, entry and a city sidewalk. In all cases, firms quoted either per attendance at the home or per month (i.e. not per hour).

The twenty-six lawn care firms in Calgary charged an average of $29.71 per attendance (with the majority between $25 and $35) and the thirteen firms in Edmonton averaged $36.15 (with the majority between $30 and $40). With respect to snow removal, the six Calgary firms that charged per attendance averaged $26.67, whereas the five Edmonton firms averaged $33.80. One Calgary firm charged a flat rate of $100 per month and one charged $140 per month.

4. Child care

We identify five methods of providing (commercial) child care: day care, day home, live-in nanny, live-out nanny, and before- and after-school care. We obtained all of our information from various internet sites.

The numbers of day cares and day homes that were contacted in Calgary and Edmonton, and their average monthly fees, are reported in Table 1. There it is seen that day homes charge approximately $650 to $700 per month for all ages of children; and that day cares charge approximately $1,000 per month for infants and from $750 to $900 for other age groups.

 

The average monthly rate for the thirteen live-in nannies we identified in Calgary was $1,763; and for thirteen live-out nannies (also in Calgary) the rate was $1,683. In Edmonton, many nannies reported hourly rates. Assuming that those rates applied to forty-hour weeks, the ten live-in nannies charged an average of $1,770 per month and the eleven live-out nannies charged $1,912.

The average monthly rate for before- and after-school care was found to be $401 in Calgary and $415 in Edmonton.

5. Home care & meal preparation

We were able to identify four agencies in Calgary that provide generalized home care services, such as meal preparation, light housekeeping, grocery and clothes shopping, grooming and dressing, bed-making, and bathing. In each case, we sought a quote for “a relative that had been injured in an accident and was recuperating at home.” The average hourly rate among these agencies was $24.81.

In Edmonton, we found only one agency (We Care), which charged $27.75 per hour. However, we also identified two individuals on Kijiji, who charged $14.00 per hour and $15.00 per hour, respectively.

 

6. Summary

In this article, we have reported the results of a survey of household services providers in Alberta. Two outcomes are very clear. First, it is inappropriate to use a single, hourly rate to evaluate all such services. Whereas child care services cost approximately $5.00 per hour per child (assuming that nannies care for two children on average), housecleaning services cost more than $25 per hour, and lawn care and snow removal can cost over $30 per visit.

Second, the convention of using $12 to $16 per hour for household services is insupportable. All of the services that were identified in our survey either cost significantly less that that – for example, childcare – or significantly more – for example, housecleaning, lawn care, and handyman services.

These findings strongly support the view that hourly rates for housekeeping services should not be obtained by averaging the figures that have been adopted in previous cases. We are pleased to note that by Madame Justice D. C. Read agreed with our conclusion on this point in her decision in Palmquist v. Ziegler, 2010 ABQB 337, at para [271] (emphasis added):

By using an average of numbers accepted in other cases in order to establish a number used to make an assumption in this case, all of the possible errors, either of the trial judge or of the economists who gave evidence in those cases, are incorporated into the number to be used in this case. Courts rely upon economists to determine what assumptions are reasonable to make and their decisions are only as reasonable as are the assumptions used. I have no means of evaluating the expert evidence that was before those other courts to determine whether or not I accept the assumptions made. It is circular to accept that an average of numbers accepted by another courts has any validity in respect to the issue of what economic assumptions are reasonable for me to make in this case.

Our findings also suggest that it may be inappropriate to rely on the wage rates reported by Statistics Canada to estimate the costs of services such as housecleaning. Whereas the wages for that occupation average approximately $15 per hour, the individual housecleaners we identified through Kijiji and Craigslist charged more than $22.00 per hour on average; and housecleaning agencies charged more than $30 per hour (more than twice the wage that Statistics Canada reports).

7. Proposal

Statistics Canada provides data concerning the amounts of time spent on six types of “household work and related activities.” These are: cooking/washing up, house cleaning and laundry, maintenance and repair, other household work, shopping for goods and services, and primary child care. For the purposes of calculating the costs of household services, we propose to combine “cooking/washing up” with “shopping” and evaluate that category at the approximate average rate for home care and meal preparation, $25.00 per hour (up from $20.00 per hour in our 2005 survey).

We will combine “maintenance and repair” with “other household work” (a large portion of which consists of “gardening and ground work”) and evaluate the resulting services at the landscaping, snow removal, and handyman services rate of approximately $30.00 per hour (down from $32.00 in 2005).

We will evaluate “house cleaning and laundry” at the rate for housecleaning services. For the purposes of our reports, we propose to use the conservative rate of $30.00 per hour in Calgary and Edmonton, and $20.00 per hour elsewhere (compared to $25.00 and $20.00, respectively, in 2005).

Finally, we will assume that it costs $850 per month to care for each baby (the approximate mid-point of day care and home care costs), $800 to care for each toddler/pre-school child, and $400 per month to provide after-school care for each school-aged child (up from $700, $600, and $275, respectively, in 2005).

leaf

Christopher Bruce is the President of Economica and a Professor of Economics at the University of Calgary. He is also the author of Assessment of Personal Injury Damages (Butterworths, 2004).

The Cost of Household Services, Alberta, 2006: A Survey

by Christopher Bruce and Amelia Lamb

This article first appeared in the summer 2006 issue of the Expert Witness.

In 1997 and 1999, Economica conducted surveys of the cost of obtaining household services. At that time, we found that housecleaners in Calgary and Edmonton charged approximately $13.50 per hour; and that handymen charged approximately $24.00 per hour.

Since that time, we have estimated the current costs of household services by increasing the 1999 estimates by the intervening rate of wage inflation in Alberta. This implies, for example, that our estimate of the cost of housecleaners was approximately $16.00 per hour in 2005.

Increasingly, however, we have become aware that our estimates differ from the rates that prevail in Alberta, particularly in Calgary and Edmonton. The informal evidence available to us suggests, for example, that most housecleaners charge significantly more than $20 per hour.

For this reason, in late 2005 and early 2006 we conducted a new survey of household costs. In this survey, we obtained housecleaning, handyman, landscaping and snow removal, child care, and home care/meal preparation rates from a large sample of agencies and individuals in both Calgary and Edmonton, and housecleaning rates for smaller samples in Lethbridge, Grande Prairie, and Red Deer. We report the results of that survey in this article.

Housecleaning

Using newspapers and the Yellow Pages, we identified thirteen individuals or agencies in Calgary and ten in Edmonton that provide housecleaning services. We asked each of them to provide their hourly rate to clean a 1,600 square foot, two-story house (assuming there were not pets and that the cleaner would not be responsible for the basement). In Calgary, the average rate was $28.00 per hour ($26.22 if the top two rates are excluded), with a range from $21.25 to $38.00. As can be seen in Table 1, the most common rates (from seven agencies) were in the range of $24.00 to $27.50 per hour. Two of the thirteen rates were from individuals, who quoted $22.50 and $24.00 per hour, respectively.

In Edmonton, the average rate was slightly lower, at $26.10 per hour ($24.77 without the top rate); and the most common rates (from six agencies) ranged from $22.00 to $25.00 per hour. (See Table 1.)

Table 1

We were less successful at obtaining quotes in the other regions, obtaining only three in Lethbridge, two in Red Deer, and one in Grande Prairie. In those cities, the average hourly rates were: Lethbridge, $17.00; Red Deer, $21.00; and Grande Prairie, $22.50.

With the sole exception of the $17.00 figure for Lethbridge, it is seen that all of these figures significantly exceed the $16.00 rate that we estimated by increasing the 1999 rate by the average rate of wage inflation in Alberta.

We suspect that there are two reasons for the deviation of our predicted estimates from the actual figures, as indicated by the survey. First, it may be that the wages of individual housecleaners have been rising more quickly than the average. Second, anecdotal evidence suggests that the housecleaning sector has increasingly become dominated by professional agencies, whose hourly rates exceed the wages they pay to their employees, (in many cases by a significant margin).

This raises an important question: if employees are being paid, say, $14 to $17 per hour, and agencies are charging $25 to $35 per hour, why don’t individual cleaners leave their current positions and set up in competition with their former employers? Why doesn’t a worker who has been earning $15 per hour advertise his or her services at $20 to $30 per hour?

We suspect that the answer to this question derives from three factors. First, many cleaner-employees may lack the business skills to allow them to establish their own companies. These individuals may prefer to work for a company that offers them guaranteed hours and wages, as low as those wages may be, rather than take the risks of setting up their own firms.

Second, commercial firms often incur costs – for example, for cleaning supplies, advertising, insurance, transportation, administration, and employee bonding – in excess of the wages they pay to their employees. Individuals who established their own businesses would have to bear these costs themselves.

Finally, commercial firms may be better able than individual cleaners to develop reputations for reliable service. If a cleaner is sick or otherwise unable to work, a firm can often replace that individual with another employee; whereas if self-employed individuals are unable to meet their commitments, their jobs go undone. Customers may be willing to pay a premium for the more reliable service.

Regardless of the answer to this question, however, the fact is that it would be very difficult to hire a reliable housecleaner in Calgary or Edmonton for less than $20 per hour – and the expected cost is closer to $26 to $28 per hour.

Handyman

We obtained the names of handyman services in Calgary and Edmonton from newspapers and the internet. In each case, we asked agencies to quote for the hourly rate to either paint an interior room or repair a deck. The results are reported in Table 2. With the exception of one “outlier,” a $15.00 per hour rate quoted by a non-bonded, uninsured, non-professional student company, the rates in both cities fell consistently in the $30.00 to $40.00 per hour range, with an average of approximately $33.00 per hour in both cities.

Table 2

Landscaping and snow removal

Landscaping and snow removal firms were identified online or from the Yellow Pages. In the case of landscaping, firms were asked for their hourly rates to mow lawns and conduct yard clean-up. The four firms we identified in Edmonton had slightly higher hourly rates, approximately $38.00 per hour, than did the seven firms surveyed in Calgary, where the average was approximately $33.00 per hour. (See Table 3.) It is possible that the difference between the two cities arose simply from the small sample size in Edmonton.

Table 3

Child care

There are two primary methods of providing (commercial) child care: nannies, who come in to the home, and day care. We obtained information about nanny services online and from the newspapers; information about daycare services was obtained from the Yellow Pages.

In Table 4, we provide information about “live-in” and “live-out” nannies in Calgary. Unlike Tables 1-3, we do not present information about individual rates, as we collected 30 observations. Rather, we report the number of observations in each of a number of ranges.

Table 4

The first column in Table 4 represents monthly rates that were offered in advertisements in the Calgary Herald by families who were seeking to hire nannies. The second column represents rates that private nanny agencies charge for placements.

We also obtained some information concerning the cost of nannies in Edmonton. (These data are not reported in tables as we had insufficient responses.) As in Calgary, the one nanny placement service we were able to identify charged $1,510.82 per month; and the hourly rate for (private) live-out nannies were from $8.00 to $16.00 per hour, with an average of approximately $11.75.

With respect to live-in nannies, the private and commercial rates were in agreement, at approximately $1,500 per month, or approximately $8.00 per hour. (Employers are required to pay at least the minimum wage for 44 hours per week, or $1,510.82 per month.) With respect to live-out nannies, however, private rates in Calgary, at $1,360 per month, were significantly less than commercial rates, at $2,220 per month, (or $11.50 per hour).

We suspect that the commercial rates in Calgary are more reliable estimates of the actual costs than are the private. First, the private rates in Edmonton are virtually identical to the commercial rates in Calgary. And, second, although we would anticipate that live-in nannies, who receive room and (some) board, would be paid less than live-out nannies, who have to pay their own room and board, the live-in rates offered in the Calgary newspapers were more than live-out rates.

With respect to day care services, (Table 5), we found that, for the youngest children, there was a significant concentration of fees around $700 per month and another concentration around $800, with an overall average of $720 (pre-toddlers) to $740 (babies) per month in Calgary, (or approximately $4.00 per hour per child), and $630 to $855 per month in Edmonton. As we found only three day care centres that would look after babies in Edmonton, we prefer the Calgary figure. The pre-toddler figure appears to be lower in Edmonton than in Calgary because of the presence of a number of centres associated with the YMCA that provide low-cost care for this group.

Table 5

With respect to older pre-school children, we found that almost half of the agencies charged between $600 and $630 per month, with an overall average of $590 to $625 (approximately $3.00 per hour).

In Table 6, we report day care charges for pre- and after-school care for school-age children in Calgary. It is seen there that the most common rate is $300 per month, with an average across 23 agencies of $280. The two agencies we identified in Edmonton charged $335 and $320, respectively.

Table 6

Home care and meal preparation

Through the Yellow Pages and the internet, we were able to identify six agencies in Calgary that provide generalized home care services, such as meal preparation, light housekeeping, grocery and clothes shopping, grooming and dressing, bed-making, and bathing. Five of these six agencies charged between $21.00 and $23.00 per hour, with the sixth charging $17.95. If the latter is excluded, the average hourly rate was $22.00. We were unable to obtain rates for similar services in Edmonton.

Calgary’s Kerby Center also provided us with a list of six agencies that would prepare meals at home. Five of those six charged between $15.00 and $20.00 per hour, with an average of $17.50. The sixth agency charged $30.00 per hour, but was operated by a nutritionist who would design healthy menus, in addition to preparing meals.

Summary

In this article, we have reported the results of a survey of household services providers in Alberta. Two outcomes are very clear. First, it is inappropriate to use a single, hourly rate to evaluate all such services. Whereas child care services cost approximately $3.00 to $4.00 per hour per child (assuming that nannies care for two children on average), housecleaning services cost more than $25 per hour, and handyman and gardener services cost approximately $33 per hour.

Second, the convention of using $12 to $16 per hour for household services is insupportable. All of the services that were identified in our survey either cost significantly more than that or significantly less.

Proposal

In its publication As Time Goes by . . . Time Use of Canadians (Catalogue 89-544-XPE) Statistics Canada provides data concerning the amounts of time spent on six types of “household work and related activities.” These are: cooking/washing up, house cleaning and laundry, maintenance and repair, other household work, shopping for goods and services, and primary child care. For the purposes of calculating the costs of household services, we propose to combine “cooking/washing up” with “shopping” and evaluate that category at the approximate average rate for home care and meal preparation, $20.00 per hour.

We will combine “maintenance and repair” with “other household work” (a large portion of which consists of “gardening and ground work”) and evaluate the resulting services at the landscaping, snow removal, and handyman services rate of approximately $32.00 per hour.

We will evaluate “house cleaning and laundry” at the rate for housecleaning services. For the purposes of our reports, we propose to use the conservative rate of $25.00 per hour in Calgary and Edmonton, and $20.00 per hour elsewhere.

We will assume that it costs $700 per month to care for each baby, $600 to care for each toddler/pre-school child, and $275 per month to provide after-school care for each primary school-aged child.

Finally, we will continue to assume that replacement workers for the non-childcare services will perform these tasks more efficiently than the plaintiff would have. Specifically, we will assume a 25 percent reduction in the hours requiring replacement to reflect increased productivity on behalf of hired replacements. We do not make this adjustment for the childcare services, since if a child needs (say) three hours of after-school care, there is no opportunity to somehow provide this care in only 2½ hours.

leaf

Christopher Bruce is the President of Economica and a Professor of Economics at the University of Calgary. He is also the author of Assessment of Personal Injury Damages (Butterworths, 2004).

Amelia Lamb has been Economica’s office administrator since 2004.

Claims by Elderly Parents for Loss of Caregiving by Adult Children

by Hugh P. Finnigan

This article first appeared in the autumn 2005 issue of the Expert Witness.

Advancements in medical technology have prolonged the lives of individuals and dramatically increased their costs of care. As a result, many adult children accept at least some responsibility in the provision of such care to their aging parents. This leads to a possible claim by elderly parents for the loss of caregiving services, if an adult child is seriously injured or killed.

Before such a claim can be made, however, some determination must be made of the probability that an adult child will offer such care, especially if the parent had not been in need of assistance before the child was injured. In this article I shall review some recent American research that examines the factors that determine whether an adult child will care for an elderly parent.

In an early study, Stone, Cafferata, and Sangl (1987) examined 1982 data to develop a profile of caregivers by their relationship to the care recipient. The researchers found that the average age of these caregivers was 57.3. Moreover, one-third of these caregivers were still employed and having to make adjustments to their work schedules. One-third of the caretaker’s families were near or below the poverty line. Finally, one-third of the care providers were themselves in only fair to poor health.

Several researchers have examined opportunity cost as a possible motivation. That is, children might find that the expense of caring for their elderly parents exceeds what they themselves could earn in the workplace. Thus, they might be economically better off to care for their parents in lieu of working a traditional job. Supporting this theory, researchers have found that adult women in particular tend to reduce their hours of paid work (or leave the labour force altogether) to provide care for their parents. This finding is consistent with the persistent wage differentials found between women and men. If women tend to earn less than men, on average, they face a lower opportunity cost when deciding to care for their parents.

It has also been argued that children might feel differently towards their parents, depending on the latter’s marital status. Pezzin and Schone (1999), for example, found that divorced men were less likely to receive care or financial assistance from their children than were divorced women. Moreover, if the divorced father does receive care the number of hours is often lower than that received by mothers or widowed fathers. These findings were later confirmed by Pelkowski (2005).

Pelkowski also found a number of other determinants that had not been measured by other researchers. Most importantly, she found that if the children lived within close proximity (within 10 miles) to their parents there was a far greater chance they would provide care. Also, males with living sisters tended to have a low propensity to provide assistance to their parents. Finally, Polkowski is able to answer a question posed earlier by Folbre and Nelson (2000): in her survey the expectation of a bequest was found not to be an important determinant of a child’s willingness to provide care to an elderly parent.

References

Levit, Katharine R.; Cowen, Cathy A.; Lazenby, Helen C.; McDonnell, Patricia A.; Sensenig, Arthur L.; Stiller, Jean M. and Won, Darlene K. “National Health Spending Trends, 1960-1993.” Health Affairs, Winter 1994, 13(5), pp. 14-31.

Nancy Folbre & Julie A. Nelson, 2000. “For Love or Money-Or Both?,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 14(4), pages 123-140.

Pelkowski, Jodi Messer, 2005. “Adult Children’s Propensity to Care for an Elderly Parent: Does the Marital Status of the Parent Matter? The Journal of Economics, 31(1), pp.17-38.

Pezzin, Liliana E. and Schone, Barbara Steinberg. “Parental Marital Disruption and Intergenerational Transfers: An Analysis of Lone Elderly Parents and Their Children.” Demography, August 1999, 36(3), pp. 287-97.

Stone, Robyn I.; Cafferta, Gail L. and Sangl, Judith A. “Caregivers of the Frail Elderly: A National Profile.” The Gerontologist, October 1987, 27(5), pp.616-626.

leaf

From 2003 through 2005, Hugh Finnigan was a consulting economist at Economica, with a Master of Arts degree from the University of Calgary.

An Alternative Method for Assessing the Value of Housewife Services

by Douglas W. Allen

This article first appeared in the spring 2004 issue of the Expert Witness.

Often the simplest questions in life have the most complicated answers. Such is the case in measuring the value of non-market activity like volunteer hours, leisure time, and especially the value of a housewife. How can something so much a part of our everyday experience as “household service” be such an elusive thing to evaluate … especially in court?

Of course, at the heart of the matter is the absence of explicit market pricing for housewives. “If only,” exhorts the expert economic witness, “housewives were bought and sold on an open market like wheat futures, we could have an accurate measure of their worth.” This market oriented predilection for using prices to measure value not only drives the methods currently used, it is the source of the problems in measuring, and perhaps the source of the courts often reluctance to rely on “economic” measures of worth. To paraphrase Oscar Wilde, economists often know the price of everything, but the value of nothing.

To refresh your memory, economists have argued for two different methods to measure the value of a housewife: the opportunity cost method; and the replacement cost method.

The fundamental idea behind the opportunity cost method is “what does the household sacrifice by having the wife stay home to work?” In other words, what is the opportunity cost of the housewife’s time? If a female lawyer is earning $150/hour, and she decides to forgo an hour of work to do the dishes, the cost of that task is $150. The economist then says the $150 measures the value of an hour of housewife service.

The replacement cost approach to the problem asks: “how much would it cost to replace the services of the housewife?” The idea being one could go into the market place, find the wage for nannies, cooks, prostitutes, etc., then use these wages as the value of the housewife services. Sometimes an average is used, sometimes the wage within each specialty is used.

Both of these methods are riddled with well known problems:

  • They measure the value of household services at the margin, and not the total value.
  • The OC approach assumes your hours of work are completely flexible.
  • The RC approach assumes the productivity of the wife and market replacement are the same.
  • Both methods have a hard time dealing with full-time, long-term housewives who have been separated from the labor market for years.
  • Both methods rely on often arbitrary measures of time devoted to household services.
  • Both methods are silent on how to treat housewife services that are not available in the market.
  • Both methods have a difficult time dealing with the commingling of leisure and household services.

The list goes on. Such problems are a source of income for an expert economic witness, but there must be a better way – especially for the case of the long-term, full-time housewife where using market measures is inappropriate.

The fundamental problem with both methods is that they are based on market oriented economic theory, and as a result they ignore the institutional aspect of marriage. Marriage, as an institution, is designed to produce a set of goods that the market does not produce. Certainly some market goods get jointly produced in the marriage, but these are secondary to the main purpose of marriage. Marriage restricts the behavior of both the husband and wife such that they have an incentive over their life-cycle to cooperate in procreation and the successful rearing of the next generation. To confuse the value of a housewife with the services of domestic service misses the point entirely. The market based procedures are only crude, unreliable, and biased under-estimates of the true value of a housewife.

Within the past 25 years economists have started to move away from this purely market based way of thinking, and have started to consider the institutional aspects of exchange. This work leads to an interesting method of evaluating a housewife – one that works best in the case where the market approach does poorly. This method is simple to use, and is based on the revealed spouse choice at the time of marriage as an indicator of the value of a spouse’s contribution to a marriage.

Marriage is a sharing arrangement. A husband does not hire his wife, nor does the wife hire her husband. When the marriage is doing well both benefit, and in hard times both suffer: “for better or for worse.” Some shares are better than others. A spouse who gets a small share of the pie has little incentive to work within the marriage. The gains from an increased share to this person will more than offset the disincentives caused by reducing the share to the other spouse. Economists have shown that for a given man and woman there is an “optimal share” which creates the best incentives for the husband and wife to contribute to the marriage.

The interesting thing about the optimal share is that, with one exception, it never pays the average contribution of each spouse. For example, if one spouse were contributing 90% of the marriage value and the other spouse was contributing 10%, the optimal share turns out to always be lower than 90% for the more productive spouse. This is a good deal for the low productive spouse, but a bad deal for the partner. The only time this is not true is when each spouse is equally productive and they share 50-50.

In a marriage of unequals then, to have the optimal share means that one of the spouses is unhappy. On the other hand, to share in proportion to unequal contributions means the share is not optimal and the incentives are not right: the marriage will be low valued. In either case, there is a problem.

Couples do not marry in a vacuum. Individuals compete with one another for mates. This competition for spouses, along with the optimal sharing rule above, forces people to marry individuals they expect will make an equal contribution to the marriage. A person will always do better marrying someone of equal quality and sharing equally, rather than marry someone with of a lower quality, even though their share is higher in the latter case. The result is that in equilibrium husbands match with wives who are expected to contribute equally over the life of the marriage.

This does not mean the type of contributions are the same. The husband may be expected to work in the labor force, the wife may work in the home full time. Nor does it mean the contributions actually end up equal. It simply means that the couple believes at the time of marriage that the two different streams of services are of equal value – otherwise they wouldn’t marry. Thus this approach recognizes the most valuable contribution of a full-time housewife – giving birth and raising children. The other methods, by focusing on simple household chores, ignore the most important contribution of the wife.

Recognizing the incentives of sharing within a marriage explains why marriages have a hard time surviving large unexpected shocks like infertility or long spells of unemployment. An option to divorce is to renegotiate the share. However, renegotiation, ex post, will always imply a sub-optimal share. The spouse who ends up, ex post, more productive will always be better off finding a new mate of similar productivity.

Recognizing the incentives of sharing explains why full time working wives still tend to do more than half of the housework in a marriage. Women still earn 70% of men, on average. Since total contributions must be equal in successful marriages, women who contribute less market value to the marriage must contribute more household services.

The idea that people tend to marry equals is in our popular culture. The expression “what does she see in him?” indicates that some hidden redeeming feature must be present to compensate for an observable shortcoming.

If we accept the argument that individuals marry others of equal expected value, then we have a simple, but better, method of measuring the value of household services for marriages that remain intact. If a marriage is on-going, the partners must feel that on average they are getting out of the marriage what they are putting in, and that this marriage provides a higher value than marriages to other people. The condition for this is that the partners are making approximately equal contributions and are sharing 50-50. Thus, to determine the value of household services we need only look at the market earnings of the husband and adjust for the market earnings of the wife, and the household services of the husband. Or:

Value of housewife = Husband’s incomeWife’s income + value of husband’s household services.

Suppose the wife does not work outside the home, and the husband never does any work around the house. Then the value of the wife’s household service is simply equal to the husband’s income. This methodology is not only easier than the standard ones, it is better in that it is a true measure of value, rather than just cost. It is better because it does not have any of the ad hoc aspects of the market measures since it relies on the revealed behavior of the individuals to assess their own value.

leaf

Douglas W. Allen is the Burnaby Mountain Endowed Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University

Outstanding Issues in the Valuation of Household Services

By Therese Brown and Christopher Bruce

This article was originally published in the spring 1998 issue of the Expert Witness.

In this, the final in a series of articles on the estimation of the loss of household services we discuss a number of issues which have received relatively little attention from the courts. These include:

  • the estimation of loss when the plaintiff can complete all necessary household chores, but these tasks take longer to complete than before the accident;
  • determining the age at which the loss of household services should be presumed to end; and
  • the effect of retirement on the number of hours of household services.

The Efficiency Issue

A common problem is that the injured plaintiff is sometimes still able to complete all the household chores that he or she performed prior to injury, but these tasks now take longer to complete. For instance, a female plaintiff may be able to continue with meal preparation and washing up, but whereas she had previously required 10 hours a week for this task, she finds that it now takes her approximately 15 hours a week.

One approach would be to argue that, as the plaintiff is able to “produce” the same number of household services as before her injury, she has lost nothing. However, this ignores the fact that she has lost the use of five hours per week in some other activity. Those hours may have come, for example, from hours worked or from leisure time. If it is the former, her damages could be valued using her wage rate. More commonly, however, it is leisure time that suffers, and only very rough estimates of the value of this use of time are available

A third approach, which we prefer, proceeds in two steps. First, we determine how many hours of household chores would remain to be completed if the plaintiff was to work the same number of hours in the home as she would have before the accident. Second, the cost of hiring replacement workers to perform those “missing” hours is calculated.

In the example cited above, assume that the plaintiff was to perform 10 hours of meal preparation after the accident. As she is working at only 10/15ths the speed that she had been working before the accident, she will complete in those hours, 10/15ths as much as she would have prior to the accident. That is, she will complete as many chores as she would have previously in 6.67 hours. This implies that 3.33 hours worth of chores remain to be done. It is the cost of hiring a housekeeper for this number of hours that we suggest should be used to represent the plaintiff’s loss.

At What Age Does the Loss End?

Two alternative approaches have been suggested to determine the age at which individuals would normally cease to engage in household production. The first such approach simply assumes that individuals cease to provide household services after their retirement ages. This approach is generally unsatisfactory, however, as the evidence suggests that the vast majority of seniors, some of whom may exhibit mild to moderate disability, do not require assistance with activities such as shopping or housework, the instrumental activities of daily living. Eric Moore et al, in their publication Growing Old in Canada, point to Statistics Canada data which indicates that 90.4% of men and 84.5% of women from 65 to 74 years old are in this category. Neena Chappell, in her book Social Support and Aging, argues that, while the existence of chronic health conditions is not uncommon in seniors, such conditions often do not lead to functional disability or limitations in activity.

A second commonly used approach is to continue the loss of household services only to age 80. There is considerable evidence to support this type of approach. Reference to statistical information about the living arrangements of today’s seniors, as well as their participation in household activities, makes it apparent that increasing numbers of seniors live independently to this age, requiring little or no assistance.

Herbert C. Northcott, in Aging in Alberta, makes evident the growing trend for seniors to remain in private households. While 13.4% of seniors in 1976 were institutionalised, this proportion dropped to 9.0% in 1991. Possible reasons for this decline include the increasing ability and desire of seniors to continue to live independently, as well as the shortage of institutional beds. At any rate, there is reason to suggest that the trend toward decreasing institutionalisation will continue.

Many seniors living at home do not require help with household work. The Statistics Canada publication A Portrait of Seniors in Canada makes this apparent. Of those 65 and older living at home in 1991, only 36% required assistance with housework. Fewer still required assistance with grocery shopping and yard work (31.5% and 30.0% respectively). Only 26% of this group required help with meal preparation. By far the greatest proportion of this assistance (68%) came from the individual’s spouse.

Much of the research would indicate, therefore, that not only are most seniors remaining in their own homes, but also most of them are managing to do so with little or no assistance. For this reason, it would seem prudent to recognise the extent to which most seniors are able to continue with productive contributions in the area of household services.

After age 75, however, an increasing number seniors suffer from chronic health conditions which limit their activity. An example of such an indicator is reported in the Statistics Canada Publication A Portrait of Seniors in Canada. While only 36% of 65 to 74 year-old non-institutionalised seniors reported activity restricting health problems, 46% of their counterparts aged 75 and older reported such restrictions. In addition the rate of institutionalisation does increase with advancing age. Herbert Northcott reports that in 1991, in Alberta, the rate of institutionalisation was only 2.8% for those aged 65 to but rose to 18.3% for those 75 years of age or older.

For these reasons, our approach is to seek a middle ground. It would appear that to assume that household productivity or participation in household services will decline significantly at 65 or 70 years of age would be to discount the contribution that many seniors are willing and able to make long past that arbitrarily assumed time. On the other hand, to continue the loss of household services to life expectancy would ignore the evidence that seniors in later years do increasingly face the risk of institutionalisation and activity-limiting disability. We find the statistical evidence supports the continuation of the loss of household services until approximately age 80.

Does a Change Occur in Household Services Contribution at Retirement?

Intuition suggests that the number of hours devoted to household work will decrease at retirement. This, however, is not what the statistics suggest. In fact, the contribution to household activities tends to increase significantly at retirement. An excellent source of information concerning the number of hours thus contributed is available from the Statistics Canada publication, As Time Goes By…Time Use of Canadians. For example, a married, retired male’s contribution at age 65 (3.1 hours per day) is almost double that of the married, full-time employed male’s contribution at age 45 to 64 years of age (1.7 hours per day). These available statistics can be readily used to forecast the future household contributions of the plaintiff at retirement. Our approach is to consider the number of hours that the plaintiff contributed prior to the accident and then increase them by the same percentage that the average individual’s contribution would increase, as indicated by this resource.

There may be concern expressed about this type of approach, for the reason previously mentioned, that an increase in household services at retirement may not be intuitively obvious. In our view, the approach we take – to adjust the individual’s contribution to reflect what actually occurs with individuals of the plaintiff’s ilk – is the only responsible approach to take in the interests of accuracy.

leaf

From 1996 through February 1998, Therese Brown was a consultant at Economica.

Christopher Bruce is the President of Economica and a Professor of Economics at the University of Calgary. He is also the author of Assessment of Personal Injury Damages (Butterworths, 2004).

Determination of the Hourly Cost of Household Services

by Therese Brown and Audrey Hallson

This article first appeared in the winter 1997 issue of the Expert Witness.

Articles in previous issues of The Expert Witness have dealt with the appropriate approach to the valuation of the loss of household services, as well as methods to determine the number of hours lost, and a brief look at the way that the courts have dealt with this issue. The focus of this article is the determination of the hourly rate which should be applied to the replacement cost of those household services which the plaintiff performed prior to the accident but is now unable to undertake.

On the face of it, this would seem to be a fairly straightforward process. The features which make this issue more complex become apparent when we pose certain questions, such as: What activities comprise household services? What type of provider can best replace those services which the plaintiff is now unable to undertake? Are there features which differentiate the services offered by seemingly similar service providers? Is there a standard which should be adhered to in regard to the level of service that a plaintiff should be compensated for? Is there a generalist rate that can be applied to the loss of household services which reflects the replacement cost of household services for the plaintiff?

While some of these queries lack pat answers applicable in all cases, it is our intent to give these issues serious consideration in the discussion which follows.

What are Household Services?

Anyone who has undertaken activities in or around the home is well aware that these chores are many and varied. Certain household duties come quickly to mind in this regard, for example, meal preparation, general cleaning, and laundry. There are other household activities which should also be considered, despite the fact that they may not form a large proportion of total household responsibilities. Examples would include indoor as well as outdoor maintenance.

Of interest here is the rate payable to replacement help for those services which the plaintiff is no longer able to undertake. In many instances a plaintiff continues to undertake selected household activities but his/her injury precludes participation in other activities. It is, therefore, important to compensate the individual fairly by utilising an hourly rate for a provider who actually performs the required services. The following discussion will provide a brief explanation of the services provided by various agencies or individuals who may be contracted to provide replacement help to a plaintiff.

Types of Service Providers

We find it useful to distinguish three primary types of service providers. These we call: homemakers, housecleaners, and handymen.

The primary purpose of a homemaker is to provide services which allow a person, compromised in some way, to remain in his/her own home. Homemakers generally undertake non-labour intensive housekeeping duties including light cleaning, meal preparation, grocery shopping, and laundry. These individuals would not undertake all of the general cleaning tasks required in the household. It is not the norm for homemakers to provide any of the equipment or supplies required in the performance of their duties.

Housecleaners tend to specialise in more labour intensive cleaning duties than do homemakers, and they usually provide necessary equipment and supplies. These individuals may be found either through agencies which are listed in the yellow pages of telephone directories or through classified advertisements in newspapers. The latter are more likely to be owner/operators.

Replacement services which are of a home maintenance nature would generally be provided by a handyman. These service providers may be accessed through the yellow pages or classified advertisements. They would undertake tasks such as the repair of leaky faucets, replacement of a furnace filter, or minor household repairs.

Finally, repair of automobiles and outdoor maintenance, such as lawn maintenance or snow removal, would be accomplished by service providers who specialise in those particular services.

Average Rates Charged by Service Providers

In February and March of 1997 Economica undertook a comprehensive survey of rates charged by various service providers in the Calgary and Edmonton areas. With the exception of those housecleaners who are individual providers, we have relied on prices quoted by businesses who offer their services in the yellow pages of telephone directories. The table below summarises the results of this survey. These rates are shown in terms of the cost per hour to hire the various service providers, other than average costs for lawn maintenance and snow removal services. The latter prefer to provide quotes for the total cost per season of providing the service.

The large rate differential between homemakers and housecleaners is largely explained by the fact that these providers offer services which differ from one another in a number of important ways. As previously noted, homemaker services are limited to lighter cleaning duties. The source of the rate differential between “agency” and “individual” housecleaners is less apparent. The most significant difference between these two providers is that the former are usually bonded, insured, and covered by workers’ compensation, which is generally not the case for the latter.

Household Service Provider Rates

Calgary Edmonton
Homemakers (Agency rates) $13.47/hr $13.39/hr
Housecleaners (Agency rates) $18.49/hr $17.25/hr
Housecleaners (individual providers) $13.54/hr $14.98/hr
Handyman $24.68/hr $23.32/hr
Lawn Maintenance (per season) $613.62 $589.09
Snow Removal (per season) $589.07 $637.12

Generalist Rates for Replacement Household Services

In a previous article (The Expert Witness, Winter 1996), we proposed that the technique of choice in the valuation of household services is the generalist variant of the market replacement method. An alternate valuation method, the specialist method, would base the loss on the cost of hiring various and assorted specialists to replicate the contribution previously made by the plaintiff. The concern with that method derives mainly from its impracticality. To match the rates charged by numerous specialists to innumerable household tasks which are now outside of the plaintiff’s capacity would be an almost impossible task. As such, the generalist variant remains the method of choice.

It is shown in two examples which follow that the use of one all-inclusive generalist rate is usually sufficient to accurately capture the plaintiff’s loss of household services. It is recognised, however, that the generalist rate may be oriented either toward: the homemaking type of service (including meal preparation and lighter cleaning); or the housecleaning type of service (comprising more onerous cleaning duties). Finally, a third example describes a situation in which the use of one all-inclusive generalist rate may be inadequate. In that case, it is shown that the use of the generalist rate may need to be supplemented with the use of another rate.

In the first instance, it is assumed that a severely injured plaintiff who resides in a small condominium, will require the services of an individual who will prepare meals and perform general light cleaning duties, to allow him/her to remain in his/her own home. In this case homemaking services would comprise the largest component of future replacement services, as outdoor maintenance is provided and only minimal general cleaning activities would be required in the smaller residence. It can be assumed then that the loss can be calculated according to a generalist rate based on the average cost of hiring a homemaker.

In a second instance, a plaintiff who is less severely injured is able to continue with meal preparation and light cleaning, precluding him/her only from undertaking more labour intensive cleaning duties. Thus, the relevant generalist rate would be the average hourly rate charged by housecleaners.

Finally, in a third case it may be necessary to supplement the use of a generalist rate with the rate of another service provider. For instance, it may be found that the plaintiff’s previous contribution to household services was in the area of meal preparation and home repair/maintenance, neither of which are possible now given his/her physical limitations. The replacement help required by the plaintiff would then include both a homemaker and handyman. For the former, the use of a homemakers’ rate would be representative of the generalist rate required in the calculation of the loss. This alone would not capture the plaintiff’s loss if it shown that prior to the accident he/she also contributed several hours per week to maintenance duties. In this case, the use of a handyman rate should be applied to the portion of hours which the plaintiff is no longer able to contribute toward those type of activities.

Additional Complications

As can be seen in the table of household provider rates, there is a large differential between the average rates of housecleaners hired through classified ads and those hired from agencies. It appears that this is attributable to the fact that the latter tend to be bonded, insured, and covered by workers’ compensation, which is usually not the case for the former. The implication of this additional proviso is that the customer who hires housecleaners from an agency is afforded additional protection. Protection, in part, is derived from the screening of service providers, due to their bonded status. The consumer who buys cleaning services from an agency would be covered for breakage or theft which might occur while the service provider was in his/her home. In addition, because of workers’ compensation coverage, the plaintiff would not be liable for injury that the housecleaner may incur while in the plaintiff’s home.

To some extent, then, the consumer who purchases cleaning services from an agency is choosing a service which differs from that purchased from an individual provider. Determination of the appropriate replacement rate for the provision of housecleaning services is an important issue, as it can have a significant impact on the award. It is important, therefore, to ascertain which of these rate forms the basis for adequate compensation for the plaintiff who will need to hire housecleaning replacement services.

There is yet another factor, not yet alluded to here, which further complicates the valuation of the loss of household services. This is the loss of the management component of household services. A more complete discussion of the concept of the “management or indirect labour component” of the loss of household services can be found in an earlier article dealing with judgments in the valuation of household services (The Expert Witness, Autumn 1997). Any individual who has managed a household can verify that this is essential to the success of any well-run home. In regard to this important function, however, the determination of an appropriate rate becomes increasingly difficult, as this is not a service which can be readily purchased in the market. Until an alternate approach is determined to deal with the loss of household management capabilities the loss is probably best reflected by the generalist rate for replacement help that is being used in that particular case.

The Courts

A number of recent court judgments have specified hourly rates at which the loss of household services has been valued. In Morris v. Budnarchuk (1997) Action No. 9503 04671, Sanderman J. accepted the hourly rate of $10.75 which had been applied to the pre-accident loss. The rate of $12.00 for the future loss of housekeeping services was rejected, to be replaced by the rate of $10.75 throughout. One of the points raised to support the rejection of the higher rate was that there had been no consideration given to the fact that there are people who will perform household services for minimum wage. Likewise, in Reynolds v. Pohynayko (1997) 202 A.R. 1, a proposed rate of $12.00 per hour was rejected in favour of a rate of $8.50 per hour. The rationale for this decision was that there was no need to pay agency rates for housecleaners, as housecleaning services could be hired directly. In Labbee v. Peters, (1997) 201 A.R. 241, McIntyre J. ruled $10.00 per hour to be an appropriate generalist rate at which replacement help could be hired. Other recent decisions have employed similar rates.

These decisions leave both counsel and economic experts in something of a quandary. Whereas our survey indicates that it would be difficult to find a service provider for less than $13 per hour, even from the classified ads, the courts have consistently imposed their own view that no rate above $11 is permissible. The question is: should the expert substitute a rate which has been derived employing a sound statistical methodology with one which has been chosen by a number of trial courts, but not approved by the Court of Appeal?

Some economists testifying in Alberta have answered “yes” to this question and, in the face of the evidence which they have collected themselves, have begun to recommend a rate of $10.00 to $12.00. It is our view that this approach is an abrogation of the responsibility of the expert to provide the best evidence possible. Of course, should the legislature or the courts mandate a particular rate, as has been done with respect to the discount rate in most provinces, the expert would be obligated to adopt that rate regardless of the evidence.

Summary

This discussion has expanded on the use of the generalist method in the determination of the loss of household services. Assigning an appropriate rate to the loss of household services may have a large impact on an award for the loss of household services. Given this reality, it is important to look closely at the nature of a plaintiff’s loss of household services. In most cases, the loss can be valued at one all-inclusive generalist rate. This necessitates the determination of whether the generalist’s role is to provide access to homemaking services of a non-rigorous nature or housecleaning services which are more labour intensive. In reference to the latter, it must then be determined whether the plaintiff’s needs are met by the services of an individual provider or whether a housecleaner hired through an agency is more appropriate.

It has been noted that the rates applied to the loss of household services in the courts are not consistent with the rates charged by the service providers contacted in our survey. There is considerable discrepancy especially between the rates suggested by recent court decisions and the rates of housekeeping agencies which we surveyed. This would imply that plaintiffs are not being compensated at a rate which would allow them to hire replacement workers who are bonded, under the auspices of a licenced business. It may be argued that the plaintiff should have access to bonded replacement workers from a licenced agency, thus leaving him/her relatively less vulnerable in regard to the increased potential of theft or breakage of personal property, and exposure to a liability claim from an injured worker. If there is validity to that claim, it may be argued that the use of an agency rate in the valuation of a household services claim is necessary to restore the plaintiff to his/her pre-injury status.

Finally, there are instances when the use of one generalist rate may result in inadequate compensation. In those cases, a more complex approach is necessitated, whereby the plaintiff’s loss is valued according to the cost of replacement help for more than one type of service. Given that this would make the calculation of the loss more complex, it would be advisable to pursue this route only if the plaintiff’s loss of capacity in categories outside of basic homemaking/housecleaning services forms a significant portion of the loss.

leaf

From 1996 through February 1998, Therese Brown was a consultant at Economica.

From 1995 through December 1998, Audrey Hallson was the office assistant at Economica. She also assisted with Economica’s newsletter, and conducted research.

Notable Judgments in the Valuation of Household Services

by Therese Brown

This article first appeared in the autumn 1997 issue of the Expert Witness.

This is the third in a series of articles on the loss of household services in personal injury or wrongful death actions. The previous two articles dealt with the approach to the calculation of household services (The Expert Witness, Winter 1996), and the method used to estimate the number of hours lost (The Expert Witness, Spring 1997). The purpose of this article is to provide a view of the law as revealed in a number of recent court decisions.

Establishing General Principles

Two cases in particular, Daly v. General Steam Navigation Co., (1980) 3 All E.R. 696, an English Court of Appeal decision, and Fobel v. Dean (1991), 6 W.W.R. 408, a Saskatchewan Court of Appeal decision, provided precedent-setting judgments involving a claim for household services. Two main principles which are set out in Daly deal with the pre-trial and future loss of household services. First, a future loss was allowed, regardless of the intent, or lack of it, on the part of the plaintiff to hire replacement household labour to compensate for the lost capacity to undertake household work (see Daly at 701),

It is really quite immaterial, in my judgment, whether having received those damages the plaintiff chooses to alleviate her own housekeeping burden … or whether she chooses to continue to struggle with the housekeeping on her own and to spend the damages which have been awarded to her on other luxuries…

This reasoning was later advocated by Justice Vancise in Fobel and subsequently in recent Alberta cases (for instance see, McLaren v. Schwalbe (1994) 16 Alta. L.R. 108 at 138).

In Daly, it was deemed appropriate, to utilise the cost of hiring replacement domestic help to measure the damages, at least in terms of the future loss. In reference to the pre-trial period, however, Bridge, L.J. stated that the cost of replacement services was not an appropriate measure of the loss of housekeeping ability, which in that case was the additional difficulty experienced by the plaintiff in carrying out household duties. The loss, rather, should have been assessed as a part of the plaintiff’s general damages, and the additional pain, suffering and loss of amenity experienced by the plaintiff should be the measure of that loss. Despite this finding, the appeal court concurred with the trial judge regarding the amount of compensation, although the compensation in the lower court was based on the cost of replacement help.

In Fobel, at 423, Vancise J.A. commends the approach to the impairment of housekeeping ability taken in Daly, which awards the plaintiff for her loss of ability rather than relying on the prior “antiquated if not sexist” approach which compensated a third party for the loss of services previously provided to them by the victim. Also recognised, at 424, is the need to consider and define the notion of housekeeping capacity. Vancise J.A. notes that Daly provides a basis for this type of consideration when two major roles are delineated: first, “ordinary housework”; and second, “proper supervision of children”. Vancise J.A. takes this concept further, classifying the former type of duty as “direct labour”, the loss of which can be replaced quite readily by employing household labour, and the latter as “management or indirect labour” which encompasses the duties of a homemaker which are less tangible, such as household management and those aspects of the care of children which extend beyond physical care. The point is made that the latter is much more difficult to replace, and that it is up to the trial judge to ascertain to what extent ability has been impaired, in the case of either component. Despite this clearly enunciated view, the award did not incorporate a separate amount for the loss of “management” as evidence had not been brought forward on which to base a loss for that component.

Substantiating the Loss

While there seems to be consensus that the loss of household services is compensable, there is less agreement concerning the evidence that should be brought forward to substantiate the extent of the loss. As aptly stated by the Court of Appeal in Mason v. Peters (1982), 139 D.L.R. (3d) 104 at 110, “Precise proof is manifestly impossible, but if a basis for reasonable ascertainment of the amount of damages has been established, the court will make the assessment as best it can with what it has.”

There are instances in which the court relies on the plaintiff and/or the plaintiff’s family as the primary source of information in the estimation of the loss of household services. In one such case, Gilchrist v. Oatway (1995), 168 A.R. 56, at 66, the court based the loss on information from family members who estimated the additional household work which they had undertaken due to the plaintiff’s injury, even though they were unable to provide a detailed record of that additional contribution. In that case the evidence was taken at face value but then discounted to reflect a possible decrease in required household services, based on projected changes in family circumstances. In many cases, however, additional evidence as well as documentation has been required.

In Simmie v. Parker and Unger (1994), 164 A.R. 178, Rawlins J., at 182, ruled that the court’s minimum requirements for household services claims included: statistical data on time spent on household services by the average individual with characteristics similar to the plaintiff; specific information regarding tasks previously undertaken by the plaintiff and her/his ability to complete those tasks, post-accident, in the time available for those tasks; and time spent by paid help or family members in replacement of the plaintiff’s duties.

Concern regarding a lack of evidence on a household services claim was also expressed in Acheson v. Dory (1993) 8 Alta. L.R. (3d), at 145, when Picard J. stated that additional evidence that could have been provided would have included “the length of time she was totally and then partially incapacitated and the quantum and nature of the assistance required.” Further, at 146, Justice Picard listed other information pertinent to the establishment of the loss:

…the specific tasks the plaintiff can no longer accomplish or only with assistance, the standard of housekeeping she has maintained and seeks to continue, the modifications she can make to allow her to achieve her standards, the number of hours she and her husband worked in her home prior to the accident and the number she now works, the number of hours she believes she will need assistance.

Experts’ Evidence as to Loss of Hours

Another important factor in the determination of damages for the loss of household services is the acceptance of evidence offered by experts. In Grimard v. Berry et al., (1992), 102 Sask. R. 137, Maurice J., at 152, states that it must be understood that, as expert witnesses are partisan witnesses, it is imperative that their conclusions be supported by the evidence. In this case, the court determined that the estimated requirement for household services according to the plaintiff’s experts ran contrary to medical evidence that the plaintiff was still able to undertake light housekeeping duties. As a result, damages were calculated only on the inability to complete heavier housework. In other cases, the loss of household services may be adjusted in light of other factors in the plaintiff’s life. In Mackie v. Wolfe (1994), 153 A.R. 81, at 146, the claim for a loss of household services was reduced by the court on the basis of the employment circumstances of the plaintiff, as well as her active social and family life.

Reference to average statistics to support the information solicited from the plaintiff or the plaintiff’s family, as to her/his household contribution, increases the validity of that information. This was the case in Brouwer v. Grewal, (1995) 168 A.R. 1 (Q.B.), at 354, when evidence as to the plaintiff’s weekly pre-trial contribution to household services was shown to be less than the average statistics for a woman with her socioeconomic statistics, with an accompanying explanation for this discrepancy.

Similarly, there have been instances in which average statistics have formed the basis of the evidence as to household contribution, supported by testimony from the deceased’s family. In O’Hara et al. v. Belanger (1989) 98 A.R. 86, at 87, counsel for the defence argued that the employment characteristics of the deceased (extensive job-related travel) would have made it difficult for him to actively participate in household duties. Berger, J. affirmed that average statistics were, nevertheless, an appropriate basis for the estimation of the loss of services as evidence had not been brought forward to show that the deceased had not made “average” contributions.

Other approaches have also been used to support the estimated weekly requirement of household assistance. In Fobel, at 432, an estimate of the plaintiff’s level of disability, expressed as a percentage, (in that case 70 percent) was applied to the number of hours spent at household activities by the plaintiff pre-accident.

Are Household Services Replaceable and at What Cost?

In some instances, the household services which were performed by a plaintiff or the deceased cannot be replicated by replacement labour. The extent to which household services are replaceable was an issue in Taguchi v. Stuparyk (1994) 16 Alta. L.R. (3d) 72, at 84-5, when the husband of the deceased testified that a replacement worker he had hired did not actually replace his wife’s household contribution, in terms of quality. Counsel for the defendant argued to have the loss of services valued at $7 per hour, the rate paid to the teenage worker, whereas, evidence from expert witnesses valued such services as high as $23 per hour. The defendant argued that the higher commercial rates were not applicable as they incorporate overhead, profit, and additional building costs. Matheson J., stated that while commercial rates were not determinative, they were, nevertheless, “important and relevant” in this type of valuation. On that basis, the award for the future loss of household services was calculated according to an hourly rate of $12 which was described as being representative of the middle ground.

A related subject, regarding the adequacy of compensation, refers back to the discussion in Fobel with regards to the two components of the loss of household services: direct labour, including most general housekeeping duties; and management or indirect labour. Various judgments have considered a loss in either one or of both components in an award for a loss of household services. Marshall J. noted, in Brouwer v. Grewal and Edmonton (City), (1995), 168 A.R. 342, at 353-4, that the assessment of the plaintiff’s loss must consider not only her loss of ability to perform manual tasks but her ability to perform the management function of homemaking, remarking particularly on her difficulty with decision-making on basic decisions such as meal-planning. A rate of $13.31 per hour was relied on to calculate the award for the loss based on a survey of companies and individuals who provide housekeeping services.

The difficulty posed by the assessment of loss in regards to the management component of housekeeping services is made apparent by Matheson J., referring to Fobel, in Taguchi, at 86, “commercial rates in evidence here still only compensate the plaintiffs for the ‘direct labour’ aspect of housekeeping loss while the ‘management’ aspect discussed by Vancise J.A. … remains as a loss which is difficult to quantify and therefore compensate.”

Assumptions

There have been judgments, in which household services awards have reflected various assumptions about family circumstances, the division of labour in the family, or the assigning of responsibility. In Mayes v. Ferguson and Stettner (1992) 102 Sask. R. 250, at 258, Barclay J., decreased the potential award by 50 percent on the assumption that as the plaintiff and her husband were both working full-time and had no children they would have hired a part-time housekeeper even had the accident not occurred. Alternatively, in the case of DeMarco v. Toronto Transit Commission, (1978) 19 O.R. (2d) 691, at 694, the reduction of the award was based on the assumption that the plaintiff’s husband and sons should have assisted her when injury from the accident prevented her from fulfilling her household duties, thereby reducing the burden that was left to the plaintiff’s daughter.

There is danger inherent in basing an award on an assumption about what “should be” rather than what “is”, as pointed out in McLaren, at 136, when various non-traditional household arrangements are noted. Picard J. makes two points in regard to the use of potentially erroneous assumptions: first, that there is need for caution when relying on such assumptions; and second, that this issue once again highlights the importance of bringing forth sufficient evidence in these types of claims.

The Dependency Argument

In a fatal accident claim for loss of household services, the claim may or not be adjusted to reflect that the loss of services is offset to the extent that family members no longer have to provide household services solely for the benefit of the deceased. In Labee v. Peters and Thompson (1997) Action No. 9404-00110, at 23, the defendant’s expert argued that the household services provided to the deceased exceeded the contributions which the deceased made in this regard, so that until the deceased would have retired, there was not a loss of household services. While the loss being claimed by the defendant’s experts was reduced somewhat, the court ruled that the deceased’s spouse did suffer a loss of household services as she would have to pay for particular specialised work which her husband would have done.

Conclusion

The various judgments noted above suggest that the determination of the award for the loss of household services is not a straightforward matter. Thorough documentation, specific to the plaintiff or deceased in question, which details the loss of household services is essential. In the case of an injured plaintiff, the level of disability may differ according to different time periods. If such is the case, the number of hours requiring replacement and the type of replacement required must be clearly stated for the respective periods. Average statistical evidence can provide further support to the claim. In terms of the replacement cost for the loss of household services, it is prudent to rely on the cost of employing household labour in the locale where the plaintiff resides. As the loss of household services may be comprised of a “management” as well as a “direct labour” component, the loss of both aspects of household services should be considered. Since the loss of household services is not straightforward, the extent of the loss may be difficult to prove. It is crucial, therefore, to ensure that a claim for this loss is supported by thorough documentation and statistical evidence.

leaf

From 1996 through February 1998, Therese Brown was a consultant at Economica.

Determination of Contribution to Household Services

By Therese Brown

This article was originally published in the spring 1997 issue of the Expert Witness.

Quantification of an individual’s, or an estate’s, loss of household services in such a way as to return the plaintiff to their pre-injury status involves the estimation of hours contributed prior to the accident, currently, and in the future. Determination of this loss would appear to be a clearcut matter of identifying the individual’s contribution prior to the accident, and reducing this pre-accident contribution, in the case of an injured party, to the extent that s/he is still able to perform those duties. In reality, however, the process of estimating, after the fact, the extent to which an individual has contributed to the myriad duties required to keep a household functioning, from meal preparation to maintenance of the physical structure itself, is a matter that is neither straightforward nor obvious. Routes to procuring this type of information include undertaking individualised data collection, and accessing general statistical information. This article discusses various sources of information concerning household services including a review of the factors which influence household labour activities. In addition, pitfalls inherent in each method will be analysed and suggestions made as to the steps that may be taken to maximise the accuracy of the data.

Individualised Data Collection

When there is reliable information available detailing the extent of the individual’s past and current (in the case of an injured plaintiff) household labour contribution, the preferred source of data is that which is specific to the particular individual. Incorporation of factors unique to that individual should increase the accuracy of the quantification of the loss. With this method, the plaintiff, or family members of the deceased, are asked to provide a breakdown of the household activities which were undertaken prior to the accident, by completing a Household Services form. An injured plaintiff is also asked to detail the extent to which s/he is able to participate in household activities currently, as well as information about her/his contribution immediately after the accident and in the interim period if that information differs from that in the other two periods.

Family members or replacement help may assume some of the household responsibilities for which the injured person or deceased was previously responsible. A tally of the hours of household services performed in either case is not necessarily an accurate estimate of the number of hours requiring replacement. There is no assurance that replacement help, due to the expense of that service, or family members, due to lack of time, can assume all of the duties which the individual is now unable to complete. This type of information would, therefore, only be used to quantify the loss if other individual-specific information was unavailable.

There are potential hazards inherent in this type of information gathering One commonly noted quandary is the tendency to overestimate the individual’s contribution. It is important to recognise the difficulty of estimating the time devoted to the functioning of the household in a prior period It is useful to remember, as well, that an individual’s view of this type of contribution is based on their personal perspective, making this type of estimate very subjective in nature. Also, time may inadvertently be allocated more than once, as more than one household activity may be performed concurrently. For example, an individual may prepare a meal while attending to a child.

Various steps can be taken to ensure that the information elicited is as accurate as possible. First, to circumvent the possibility of double-counting, we advise the individual who is completing the form to list the activity that they consider to be their primary activity at that time, and to disregard any secondary activities which they may also be involved in. Also the respondent is asked to consider the hours devoted to household activities in the context of the entire day. It is readily apparent, should the total exceed 24 hours, that there is a need for adjustment. It may well be that the individual made a contribution which exceeds that of the average individual. If there are sound reasons for this assumption, however, the factors which create that unusual situation must be stated to support that claim. If, on the other hand, aspects unique to that individual do not justify an above-average claim an investigation of this anomaly is necessitated.

Data Analysis Based on National Statistics

Statistical averages detailing the number of hours contributed by adult Canadians to household services is available from surveys conducted by Statistics Canada on the time usage of Canadians. The most recent of these, the General Social Survey of 1992, relies on the diary approach to measure the use of time. The diary approach, which requires that survey participants complete a chronological log of their activities, is generally considered to be more accurate than the direct approach, which simply asks those surveyed to recount the amount of time which they spent at various activities over a particular reference period (Households’ Unpaid Work: Measurement and Valuation, Statistics Canada Publication 13-603E, No. 3, 22-23). Nearly 9,000 survey participants, who were required to be 15 years of age or older and living in private households, responded to the 1992 survey, which was conducted over a twelve month period on different days of the week, to ensure representative results. The unpaid work reported by those surveyed is classified into five broad areas. The first four: domestic work; help and care; management and shopping; and transportation and travel are said to comprise household work.

The breakdown provided by Statistics Canada on this survey information provides an analysis of household activities according to gender, labour force status, family and child status, and age (with those 15 years of age and older separated into five different age groups). We are, therefore, able to use average estimates across those individuals with characteristics most similar to those of the plaintiff or deceased over various stages of their life.

Factors Affecting the Amount of Unpaid Work

The principle determinants of an individual’s daily activities have been found to be their main activity (ie. full- or part-time employment, student, not employed), sex, marital status, the presence of children (the age of the youngest if there are children), and, for seniors, living arrangements. Factors such as labour force status and the presence of children influence the time spent on unpaid work, particularly for women (Households’ Unpaid Work: Measurement and Valuation, Statistics Canada Publication 13-603E, No. 3, 48). David Ciscel and David Sharp (Journal of Forensic Economics, 8(2), 1995, 120-21) also note the importance of residency and consumption status as factors that affect time use. They note that for some families home ownership may induce an increased commitment to household labour of 10 percent. The authors make an inference about a family’s consumption pattern by assuming that those families who eat together more than four days a week tend to substitute household production of domestic services for the purchase of those services in the market. Not surprisingly, those families who substitute household for market production devote more hours to household activities, especially in households where only the husband participates in the paid labour force. In families of that type, the number of hours which the wife commits to household work is almost double that of other families.

Remaining Problematic Issues

Another issue which may be problematic is the determination of the proportion of household activities that is compensable, in the instance of household activities which contribute to the functioning of the family home but may also be classified as a hobby for the individual. The example of an individual who has participated in gardening as part of her/his contribution to the household illustrates this well. It may be argued that a portion of the time spent on this activity constitutes a loss of enjoyment rather than a loss of household services, implying a non-pecuniary loss. Following through with this approach necessitates the determination of what portion of the loss of gardening ability can be claimed under the head of damages of the loss of household services.

A different approach is suggested by Janet Yale, in her article “The Valuation of Household Services in Wrongful Death Actions” (University of Toronto Law Journal, 1984, 296). She contends that the enjoyment derived by an individual as they execute a particular activity has no impact on the loss experienced by her/his family when s/he is no longer able to undertake that activity. This implies that the lack of fresh garden produce results in the same loss whether the individual considered gardening to be an onerous task or an enjoyable activity.

The potential for complexity becomes apparent if we extend this illustration of the avid gardener. It may be argued that the value of the fresh produce provided to the family is significantly less than the value of the time that the gardener invested in her/his production. This begs the question of whether compensation is required for the full extent of the time spent at this activity. While this may be an interesting point, in theory, it would be unusual for the estimated value of an individual’s time to vastly exceed the value of her/his production, thus, impacting the total claim. This situation would have to be dealt with, on a case by case basis, when it does arise. In this example, for instance, support for the claim which would include all hours spent gardening could be found by considering the value placed by that particular family on the loss of the individual’s ability to garden. This may be achieved by estimating the cost of buying produce that meets the standard of quality that the individual and their family had been accustomed to, for example pesticide-free, fresh produce which has not been damaged in transport. In the instance that support could not be found to support the claim, in an extreme case, then a downward adjustment of time spent on this activity may be warranted, referring to average statistical information.

When First-Best Is Not Possible

When quantifying the loss of household services, at Economica, we prefer, to the extent that such information is available, to rely on individual-specific information. Even when this information is available its usefulness may be limited to a certain period. We may, for instance, base our quantification of the plaintiff’s loss on the response to our Household Services form, as it applies to the current period. This information, however, may not be relevant for future periods. For instance, if the individual had young children at the time of the accident, the household labour required for that period would be greater than that required for subsequent periods but it would be almost impossible for the individual to project the exact magnitude of the difference. In that case, the percentage decrease which the average individual, with characteristics similar to the plaintiff, experiences when undergoing a similar change in family status would be applied to the base number of hours that the plaintiff currently spends on household services. This allows us to project future requirements based on information specific to that particular plaintiff.

Lifestyle changes aside, there are other instances when average statistics must be relied on to project the future requirement of a plaintiff. If for instance, it had been the plaintiff’s intention to change her/his employment status from full-time to part-time work their contribution to the household would have changed in a way that would be difficult to estimate. The percentage difference on the time spent on household activities by a full-time compared to a part-time employee could then by applied to the information specific to the plaintiff.

Conclusion

To summarise, the preferred method in estimating the extent of an individual’s contribution to household services is to rely on data that is specific to the plaintiff, or the deceased in the case of fatal accident actions. While there are potential weaknesses in this method, as previously discussed, steps can be taken to minimise the potential for inaccurate estimates. To this end, based on past experience and current research, we have revised our Household Services form to make it a more useful tool in eliciting pertinent information. There are instances when this information is unavailable, or when it will not be relevant at some future point, for example, due to lifestyle changes. In these cases, average statistics form the basis for quantification of the loss or adjustment of individual-specific information. In situations where average statistics must be used exclusively, we suggest that this generic information can be used as a reasonable substitute with confidence. This generic information should, however, be viewed primarily as a tool to support or adjust individual-specific data, which remains the data source of choice.

leaf

From 1996 through February 1998, Therese Brown was a consultant at Economica.

The Valuation of Household Services – Conceptual Issues

by Therese Brown

This article first appeared in the winter 1996 issue of the Expert Witness.

Since individuals make valid contributions through their efforts at both paid and unpaid work, the courts have concluded that they should be compensated when they are unable to pursue either type of employment. In the field of personal injury litigation this has implied that calculation of a plaintiff’s damages should include the loss (or impairment) of the individual’s ability to perform household services. Controversy remains, however, concerning the method which should be used to establish the economic value of that loss.

Three frequently discussed household services valuation methods will be explored here: the opportunity cost method, and both the generalist and specialist variants of the market replacement method. Each of these wage-based methods will be defined and the advantages and disadvantages associated with each of them will be outlined. It will be argued that there are sound reasons for the courts to have frequently adopted the generalist variant of the market replacement approach in personal injury cases.

The Opportunity Cost Method

Valuation of household services utilizing the opportunity cost method is based on the assumption that when an individual chooses to undertake unpaid work, such as household activities, the possibility of spending that time at paid work is precluded. Thus, the salary associated with that employment is foregone. Wages sacrificed to allow the individual to spend time at unpaid work are thus said to be representative of the economic value that the individual places on the unpaid activity. For example, if the individual has chosen to give up 20 hours a week of employment paying $10 per hour, in order to engage in 20 hours of housework, the opportunity cost approach concludes that the value of that housework must have been at least $10 per hour. Ten dollars becomes the valuation of an hour of housework.

There are various problems associated with adopting the opportunity cost method to valuate household services, not the least of which is the determination of the wage that has been sacrificed to allow the individual to participate in unpaid work. Janet Yale has delineated some of these concerns in her article, “The Valuation of Household Services in Wrongful Death Actions” (University of Toronto Law Journal, 1984, 303). She notes that it is reasonably simple to estimate the foregone market wage in the case of an individual who has had recent labour market experience, who has clearly defined skills, or who belongs to a particular profession. Outside of this framework, the estimation of an appropriate market wage may become extremely difficult.

More problematic is the assumption, underlying the opportunity cost method, that the amount which must be spent to restore the plaintiff to his/her pre-accident position is the value which the plaintiff had placed on the household services which have been lost. Although the individual may have given up $20 per hour to engage in housework, that individual can, in principle, be compensated for his/her loss by employing a third person to perform the forgone tasks. If a maid service can be hired to wash the kitchen floor for $15, it does not matter whether the plaintiff had previously foregone $6 or $60 to wash that floor – it will be equally clean in either case. (The exception to this argument occurs when the plaintiff had formerly obtained pleasure from household chores – but the compensation of this loss is properly that of non-pecuniary damages.)

The Replacement Cost Methods

The approach taken in both replacement cost methods is to value household services according to what it would cost to hire an individual who offers those services on the market. The difference between the two market substitute methods is that the generalist method assumes that these services could be replicated by an individual who does general domestic work. The specialist method, on the other hand, assumes that to replace household services it would be necessary to hire individuals with expertise in specific areas that comprise the various components of household duties.

Jamie Cassels expresses two concerns about the use of the replacement cost method in an article entitled “Damages for Lost Earning Capacity: Women and Children Last!” (The Canadian Bar Review, 1992, 488). First, he notes that homemaking is more all-encompassing than is implied when described simply as housekeeping, and as such the services of a housekeeper cannot adequately replace the contributions made by someone who is running a household. He also argues that domestic wages are depressed due to the large volume of “volunteer and vulnerable” labour provided by women in this sector. This would imply that these services have a higher value than the relevant market wages would indicate.

Selection Among Methods

The concerns identified above are representative of the various criticisms leveled at wage-based methods. For the most part these concerns are valid and in principle imply that these methods are inferior to the ultimate tool in the assessment of household services which has been identified as one that valuates the outputs of unpaid work (Households’ Unpaid Work: Measurement and Valuation, Statistics Canada Publication 13-603E, No. 3, 28). Elimination of this method, on the basis of its impracticality, leaves the choice between wage-based methods and more subjective methods of valuation. Since the latter would unquestionably lead to inconsistent results, we come back to wage-based methods. Although not flawless, these prevail as the best techniques available, in any practical sense, to facilitate the calculation of loss of household services.

Once the field is narrowed to these methods, it is necessary to identify the criteria that the method of choice must satisfy. Janet Fast and Brenda Munro have outlined several criteria which serve this purpose in their article “Toward Eliminating Gender Bias” (Alberta Law Review, 1994, 12-13). In particular they note three issues which warrant consideration when choosing an appropriate method: first, its computational complexity; second, the extent to which it achieves distributional equity; and third, how well it satisfies the objective of restoring the plaintiff (as much as is possible) to his/her pre-accident position. On this basis, Fast and Munro recommend the use of replacement cost methods in the valuation of household services in personal injury claims, as they best meet these criteria.

Of the two replacement cost methods, it may well be that the specialist variant is unmanageable in a practical sense, in addition to being less than objective. This approach necessitates a lapse into subjectivity when a particular specialist in one of various occupational fields has to be matched to certain household tasks (Households’ Unpaid Work: Measurement and Valuation, Statistics Canada Publication 13-603E, No.3, 25). Another hurdle remains after the occupational field is identified, as various factors affect the wage payable to specialists, depending on whether they are self-employed or employees, full or part-time employees, supervisors or labourers in entry-level positions, etc. Prior to calculation of the average wage an assumption must be made as to the “type” of employee under consideration. It is apparent that the determination of the wage for a specialist is not a clearcut matter.

If the specialist variant is ruled out, for practical reasons, this leaves the generalist variant of the market replacement method as the technique of choice in the valuation of the loss of household services. One concern that remains in reference to this method is that individuals who work in the domestic sector may perform household tasks more efficiently than would individuals in their own homes. Allowance is made for this increased efficiency in Economica’s calculation of the loss of household services. To reflect this efficiency differential, the estimation of hours of household services which have been lost is reduced by 25 percent, giving an approximation of the number of replacement hours required (see “Adjusting Claims for Hours Devoted to Household Chores”, in the Summer 1996 Expert Witness).

In our view, the generalist variant of the replacement method, once adjusted in this way, is the tool which lends itself best to the calculation of the loss of household services in personal injury cases. It is only when the generalist approach is clearly inappropriate, such as when the plaintiff provided services to the household which could only be replaced by a skilled tradesperson, that we would recommend use of the specialist method.

The caveat still holds, however, that an estimate derived using the replacement cost method is only as reliable as the factors used in its calculation, specifically the determination of the number of hours requiring replacement and the hourly cost of the replacement services. Both of these topics will be discussed in future issues of The Expert Witness, as will a review of court judgments dealing with the loss of household services.

leaf

From 1996 through February 1998, Therese Brown was a consultant at Economica.

Adjusting Claims for Hours Devoted to Household Chores

by Derek Aldridge

This article first appeared in the summer 1996 issue of the Expert Witness.

When a claim is made for loss of household services capacity, we are faced with the challenging task of determining the claimant’s pre-accident household service contribution, and comparing this to his or her post-accident capacity for household services. The difference between the pre- accident contribution and the current contribution represents the claimant’s loss of household service capacity. One simple way of measuring this loss is to calculate the number of additional hours that it would take a replacement worker to perform all of the tasks which the claimant can no longer do. This is the approach taken by Economica.

However, the number of additional hours that a claimant would require to complete the chores which can no longer be performed may overstate the amount of time required by replacement workers; and therefore, using this estimate without adjustment would overstate the claimant’s true loss. Accordingly, an adjustment needs to be made to accurately estimate the claimant’s loss: replacement workers will typically be more productive than the claimant, so the “loss” of household service hours must be adjusted downwards to reflect this productivity. The question one asks now is, “How much more productive are replacement workers compared to the typical claimant?” The answer to this question will guide the adjustment we need to make to the number of lost household service hours claimed. Fortunately there is research in this area which we can rely on.

In his book Economics and Home Production – Theory and Measurement (Brookfield USA: Avebury, 1993), Euston Quah estimates the efficiency of replacement household service workers (i.e., “domestic help”). Based on a survey of 167 households Quah found that for 2-member households, hired help was 64 percent more efficient than the household members. For 3-5-member households, hired help was 46 percent more efficient; and for households with 6 or more members, hired help was 33 percent more efficient. For those families without children, Quah reported efficiency gains of 62 percent. For families with 1-2 children, he found efficiency gains of 43 percent, and for families with 3-5 children, efficiency gains amounted to 40 percent.

Quah concluded that the productivity of workers hired by small households was relatively high because those households tended to hire workers only to undertake specialised tasks, such as ironing. Larger households hired less specialised, housecleaning staff. Hence, as most calculations of the value of housework assume that it is non-specialists who are being hired, we recommend that the lower productivity factors identified above, 33-40 percent, be applied. This implies that the number of “lost hours” claimed should be reduced by 25-30 percent. (A worker who is 33 percent more productive requires 25 percent fewer hours to complete a given task.)

leaf

Derek Aldridge is a consultant with Economica and has a Master of Arts degree (in economics) from the University of Victoria.